Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century

Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century

ISBN-10:
0521870224
ISBN-13:
9780521870221
Pub. Date:
04/16/2007
Publisher:
Cambridge University Press
ISBN-10:
0521870224
ISBN-13:
9780521870221
Pub. Date:
04/16/2007
Publisher:
Cambridge University Press
Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century

Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century

Hardcover

$125.0
Current price is , Original price is $125.0. You
$125.00 
  • SHIP THIS ITEM
    Qualifies for Free Shipping
  • PICK UP IN STORE
    Check Availability at Nearby Stores

Overview

This book was first published in 2007. Most countries levy taxes on corporations, but the impact - and therefore the wisdom - of such taxes is highly controversial among economists. Does the burden of these taxes fall on wealthy shareowners, or is it passed along to those who work for, or buy the products of, corporations? Can a country with high corporate taxes remain competitive in the global economy? This book features research by leading economists and accountants that sheds light on these and related questions, including how taxes affect corporate dividend policy, stock market value, avoidance, and evasion. The studies promise to inform both future tax policy and regulatory policy, especially in light of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and other actions by the Securities and Exchange Commission that are having profound effects on the market for tax planning and auditing in the wake of the well-publicized accounting scandals in Enron and WorldCom.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780521870221
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Publication date: 04/16/2007
Edition description: First Edition
Pages: 424
Product dimensions: 5.98(w) x 9.02(h) x 1.06(d)

About the Author

Alan J. Auerbach is Robert D. Burch Professor of Economics and Law, Director of the Burch Center for Tax Policy and Public Finance, and former Chair of the Economics Department at the University of California, Berkeley. He taught at Harvard and the University of Pennsylvania before moving to California. Professor Auerbach is a Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research and was Deputy Chief of Staff on the U.S. Congress's Joint Committee on Taxation in 1992. He has served as a member of the Executive Committee and as Vice President of the American Economic Association, and is a Fellow of the Econometric Society and of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. Professor Auerbach is a member of the Advisory Committee, Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce, the Revenue Estimating Review Panel of the U.S. Congress's Joint Committee on Taxation, and the Board of Academic Advisors of the International Tax Policy Forum. He is the editor or co-editor of ten books, and author or co-author of three books.

James R. Hines Jr. is Professor of Economics at the University of Michigan, Visiting Professor of Law at the University of Michigan Law School, and Research Director of the Office of Tax Policy Research at the Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan. He taught at Princeton and at Harvard before moving to Michigan in 1997. He is a Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research, and was previously an economist in the United States Department of Commerce. Professor Hines is a Research Fellow with the CESifo Research Network in Munich, Germany, and Research Director of the International Tax Policy Forum. He currently serves on the editorial boards of the Journal of Economic Perspectives, New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, second edition, Journal of Regional Science, B.E. Journals in Economic Analysis and Policy, and the Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money.

Joel Slemrod is the Paul W. McCracken Collegiate Professor of Business Economics and Public Policy at the Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan, and also serves as Director of the Office of Tax Policy Research, an interdisciplinary research center housed at the Ross School. Professor Slemrod was a National Fellow at the Hoover Institution and in 1984–85 was the senior staff economist for tax policy at the President's Council of Economic Advisers. He has also been a consultant to the U.S. Department of Treasury, the Canadian Department of Finance, the New Zealand Department of Treasury, the South African Ministry of Finance, the World Bank, and the OECD. He is a member of the Joint Committee on Taxation Revenue Estimating Board and has testified before the Congress on domestic and international taxation issues. From 1992 to 1998 Professor Slemrod was editor of the National Tax Journal. He is the editor or co-editor of ten books, and is co-author with Jon Bakija of Taxing Ourselves: A Citizen's Guide to the Debate over Taxes, now in its third edition.

Read an Excerpt

Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century
Cambridge University Press
978-0-521-87022-1 - Taxing Corporate Income in the 21st Century - by Alan J. Auerbach, James R. Hines Jr. and Joel Slemrod
Excerpt



ONE

The Effects of Taxes on Market Responses to Dividend Announcements and Payments: What Can We Learn from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut?*



Raj Chetty
University of California, Berkeley and NBER

Joseph Rosenberg
University of California, Berkeley

Emmanuel Saez
University of California, Berkeley and NBER

1. Introduction

There is a long-standing debate in the finance and public economics literatures about the role of taxation in corporate dividend payout policies. Starting with Elton and Gruber (1970), researchers have investigated whether the tax-favored treatment of capital gains relative to dividends affects excess returns on ex-dividend and announcement dates.1 The answers to these questions can potentially shed light on the efficiency consequences of dividend taxation as well as the reasons why corporations pay dividends despite their tax disadvantage, as explained in greater detail below.2 Despite substantial research, the empirical literature on this topic remains controversial (see Allen and Michaely, 2003 for a recent survey).

   This paper proposes to use the 2003 dividend tax cut in the United States to cast light on these issues. The 2003 tax cut, part of the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, eliminated most of the tax disadvantage of dividends relative to capital gains. Blouin et al. (2004) and Chetty and Saez (2005) have shown that the reform indeed raised dividend payments significantly and in particular induced many firms to initiate dividend payments. Here, we aim to investigate whether this reform had a significant effect on the ex-day and announcement-day price behavior as well. Consistent with the no-arbitrage conditions in standard models, we find that the ex-dividend day premium increased from 2002 to 2004, when the dividend tax rate was cut. Consistent with the signaling theory of dividends (and in contradiction with the agency models of dividends), we find that the excess return for dividend increase announcements went down from 2002 to 2004.

   In order to have a broader perspective and assess with greater confidence whether there was a sharp change after 2003, we construct a time series of ex-day price changes and excess returns around dividend increase announcements at an annual level since 1962 (the first year daily price data became available) for all companies in the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) data. To the best of our knowledge, despite the large number of studies on these issues, such a time series had not been constructed and examined in prior work. A number of useful findings emerge from this long-run analysis.

   First, we find that there is substantial year-to-year volatility in the annual time series of excess returns around both the ex-day and announcement day that is unrelated to tax changes. The annual variation in the time series is not simply due to idiosyncratic firm level noise, because this variation should be averaged out given the very large samples we are using. Powerful year effects (aggregate shocks) unrelated to taxes are responsible for this pattern. Unfortunately, the time-series pattern is non-monotonic and therefore is unlikely to be explained by a single change (such as the elimination of discrete pricing in the U.S. stock market) or by a gradual trend (such as the rise of the share of corporate stocks owned by pension funds). Moreover, we are unable to find a set of covariates that had much explanatory power in smoothing the aggregate fluctuations. A simple power analysis shows that even the effects of large tax reforms would be difficult to detect given the aggregate volatility of the series. We conclude that one should be careful when comparing individual years (e.g., around a reform) to detect a tax effect. The 2003 tax change illustrates this point well. As mentioned above, the ex-day premium pattern suggests a strong tax effect if one compares 2002 to 2004, but a placebo test comparing 2002 to 2000 would produce a false positive.

   Second, the long-run time pattern of the ex-day price behavior does not follow the long-run reduction in the advantage of capital gains versus dividends. Therefore, overall it is difficult to detect any robust pattern that one could attribute with confidence to a tax effect along the lines that Elton and Gruber (1970) originally proposed. More work is needed to test the various theories of ex-day price changes using the full time-series evidence rather than a focus on particular years, as has been the tradition in the literature.

   Third, consistent with the empirical results of the influential study by Bernheim and Wantz (1995), we find that the overall effect of dividend increase announcements on prices has declined over time while the tax dis- advantage of dividends has fallen. This finding supports the signaling theory of dividend payments, which argues that firms pay dividends despite their tax disadvantage in order to send a signal to the market about their profitability. However, again because of the large year-to-year variation in the time series of price effects, it is impossible to detect systematic effects around the major tax reforms in the United States since 1962, including the 2003 dividend tax cut. Therefore, the conclusion supporting the signaling theory rests on the strong assumption that no other long-term trend has driven the price effects down. However, it is quite plausible that factors other than tax changes (such as the increased availability of information about corporate activities) could have caused the secular decline in announcement premiums.

   Our general assessment is therefore that little knowledge about tax effects can be gained even from large reforms such as the 2003 tax cut because of the extreme aggregate volatility in the time series of the data. The estimates of prior studies – which obtain significant results by making strong assumptions about the functional form or statistical properties of the error terms in regressions or by focusing on particular windows around tax changes – should therefore be viewed with caution. To be clear, we are not advocating time-series analysis instead of focusing on sharp tax experiments. Rather, we argue that credible empirical analysis requires examination of whether the changes in excess returns around a tax experiment are exceptional relative to the fluctuations in a long time series.

   The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the conceptual framework and discusses previous work. Section 3 describes the data and our methodology. Sections 4 and 5 present the empirical results on ex-dividend premiums and dividend increase announcements, respectively. Section 6 describes the main methodological conclusions that we draw from this analysis.

2. Conceptual Framework and Previous Work

Dividend payments affect short-term stock price behavior in two ways. First, firms announce dividend payments about four to six weeks before the actual payment is made. Announcements of dividend initiations (by a firm starting to pay dividends) or dividend increases (by a firm already paying dividends) are generally viewed as good news and generate, on average, a positive excess return around the announcement date (see Allen and Michaely, 2003 for a survey). This is because increases in regular dividend payments are perceived by the market as a strong commitment to pay more dividends in the future. Historically, regular dividend payments (in general, quarterly, but sometimes annual or semi-annual) tend to be very smooth: Firms do not increase their dividend payments very often, and they are extremely reluctant to decrease or terminate dividend payments.

   Second, when the dividend is paid, the book value of the corporation is reduced by the amount paid out, which generates a negative excess return around the payment event. More precisely, when a corporation announces a dividend payment, it sets two key dates: the ex-dividend date and the payment date. The payment date is the date when the corporation effectively pays out the dividend and is in general about two weeks after the ex-dividend date. Dividends, however, are paid out to stockholders according to stock ownership just before the ex-dividend date (and not according to stock ownership at the time of payment). In other words, a stockholder is entitled to the dividend payment if and only if he or she owns the stock just before the start of the ex-dividend day.3 Therefore, we should expect a drop in price between the end of day preceding the ex-day (sometimes called the “cum-day” to mean that the stock is trading with the dividend on that day) and the beginning of the ex-day because those buying the stock after the beginning of the ex-day are no longer entitled to the dividend payment.

   The effects of dividend announcements and ex-dates on stock prices can be nicely illustrated with the extremely large special dividend payment of $3 per share made by Microsoft at the end of 2004. This special dividend (along with a doubling of the regular dividend) was announced on July 20, 2004.4 One can clearly see in Figure 1 that the share price rose quickly in the days surrounding the announcement (illustrated with vertical lines in Figure 1). This jump represents the “excess return” around the announcement date, which we define formally below. The ex-dividend day for the special dividend was set as November 15, 2004. Hence, all individuals and institutions owning Microsoft shares before the start of November 15, 2004 were entitled to a $3 dividend per share. The sharp drop in the price at this time is consistent with the negative excess return that we expect around the ex-date. Finally, dividend payments were made by Microsoft to those shareholders on December 2, 2004 (irrespective of whether they had sold their stock after November 15).

Display matter not available in HTML version

Figure 1.   Microsoft Dividend Announcement and Ex-Day Price Effects

   The Figure reports the daily closing prices of Microsoft shares from July 1, 2005 to December 31, 2005 from CRSP data. On July 20, Microsoft announced a doubling of its regular dividend payment as well as the payment of a very large one-time special dividend of $3 per share. The three-day window around the announcement date, which is used to estimate abnormal returns, is depicted by the first two vertical lines. The ex-day for the $3 special dividend is November 15. The drop in price from the cum-day (November 14) to the ex-day (November 15) is depicted by the third vertical line. The payment date, December 2, is also depicted by a dashed line.

   Our analysis roughly seeks to answer the question “How would the excess returns around the announcement and ex-dates in the Microsoft figure have differed if these events had occurred prior to the 2003 tax cut?” We answer this question essentially by averaging excess returns around the ex-day and announcement dates for many firms and comparing the means during different tax regimes. Because the timing of the tax change is quite important for our analysis, it will be helpful to review the details of the reform here. The Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 introduced favorable treatment for individual dividend income whereby dividends are taxed at a rate of 15 percent instead of facing the regular progressive individual income tax schedule with a top rate of 35 percent.5 The reform was officially signed into law on May 28, 2003, but was first proposed by the Bush administration on January 7, 2003.6 The tax cut on dividend income was made retroactive to the beginning of 2003. Therefore, during the first two quarters of 2003, corporations knew that dividends would face lower taxes with some probability. President Bush initially proposed a full exemption of dividend taxation at the individual level, potentially biasing pre-enactment expectations toward a larger tax reduction than what actually occurred. The tax rate on long-term realized capital gains was also reduced by the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, but the reduction was smaller, from 20 percent to 15 percent, and applied only to capital gains realized after May 28, 2003. Thus, this change reduced significantly the tax disadvantage of dividends relative to capital gains. The tax cut is scheduled to expire by 2009, but it could be made permanent during the second Bush administration.

2.1.   Ex-Dividend Day Returns and Taxes

The profit from selling at the end of cum-day (just preceding the ex-day) should equal the profit from selling at the beginning of the ex-day in order to eliminate arbitrage opportunities. In a world without taxes, this would mean that the drop in share price around the ex-day should equal the dividend per share. However, as first recognized by Elton and Gruber (1970), dividend and capital gains taxation can prevent this equality from holding. Ignoring overnight interest, the no-arbitrage condition with taxes is:

Display matter not available in HTML version

where

   PA is the stock price cum-dividend (just before the ex-dividend day starts),

   PB is the expected stock price on the ex-day,

   P0 is the stock price at initial purchase (tax base),

   D is dividend amount per share,

   tg is the tax rate on realized capital gains, and

   td is the tax rate on dividend income.

   Rearranging equation (1), we obtain:

Display matter not available in HTML version

The left-hand side of this expression is called the ex-day premium. The right-hand side variable captures the differential tax treatment of dividends versus realized capital gains and is called the ex-day tax preference ratio, which we denote by ρ. Without taxes, the premium is expected to be equal to one: The price falls by the exact amount of the dividend premium.7

   Figure 1 depicts the case of the large $3 special dividend payment from Microsoft. This special payment represented about 10 percent of the share price value and thus was large relative to day-to-day variation in stock prices, making the ex-dividend day drop in price clearly visible on the graph.8 The drop in price is $2.58, generating a premium of 0.86. This value is fairly close to the value of one predicted by equation (2) in 2004, when the statutory rates for dividends and long-term realized capital gains were equal.9

   There is a controversial debate in the literature about whether taxes actually affect the premium as in equation (2). Traditionally, the individual tax rate of dividend income has been substantially higher than the individual tax rate on (long-term) realized capital gains. Elton and Gruber (1970) estimated premiums for U.S. corporations in 1966–7 lower than one and argued that the differential tax could explain those results. Consistent with this claim, Barclay (1987) showed that the premium was not significantly different from one in the United States before the individual income tax was introduced in 1913, but it was significantly below one in 1962–5, when the tax differential was large. However, Michaely (1991) found no significant increase in the premium around the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86), which eliminated the favorable tax treatment of realized capital gains and thereby raised ρ sharply.10

   One limitation of equation (2), which could explain why it fails to explain observed premiums well, is that it assumes that all agents face the same tax rates. In practice, however, there is substantial heterogeneity in the tax preferences of shareholders, as pointed out by Michaely (1991). Table 2 reports the overall ex-day tax preference ratio weighted by share of stock ownership in the U.S. economy. The estimates are based on Poterba (2004) as well as an unpublished appendix series kindly made available to us by the author.11 Long-term individual owners in high-income tax brackets have typically faced a tax preference less than one. The tax ratio was equal to one briefly after TRA86 and again after the 2003 dividend tax cut. All non-taxable institutions – such as pension funds and individual pension accounts (IRAs and 401(k)s), nonprofit organizations, and government agencies, as well as individuals holding stock for the short term – have faced a tax ratio equal to one. In contrast, corporations have typically faced a ratio above one because only a fraction of dividend income received by a corporation is taxable and realized capital gains made by a corporation are fully taxable at normal rates.

   A number of studies (see, e.g., Auerbach, 1983 in the public economics literature or, more recently, Michaely and Villa, 1995 in the finance literature) have developed models with heterogeneous risk-averse investors. Those studies show that equation (2) can be generalized. In that case, the premium equals the average of the tax ratios weighted by risk tolerance. Kalay (1982) and Eades, Hess, and Kim (1984) point out that discreteness in prices may cause a bias in measuring the ex-day price drop relative to the dividend (until recently, the minimum tick size was one-eighth in the United States). This bias may cause the average price drop to be less than the dividend amount. In principle, these other effects should not eliminate the tax effects, but rather describe other channels that can potentially affect ex-day premiums.

Table 1.   Ex-Dividend Day Statistics and Results

 (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Year Tax Preference (ρ)Number of EventsMedian PremiumWeighted-Mean PremiumTrimmed-Mean Premium
1963 0.804,0890.950.950.95
1964 0.814,4180.950.980.97
1965 0.814,7670.910.890.85
1966 0.825,0290.890.950.90
1967 0.825,2590.850.810.84
1968 0.804,6970.880.740.69
1969 0.815,0740.740.710.67
1970 0.824,9100.710.690.66
1971 0.844,8510.810.780.76
1972 0.834,9740.850.810.85
1973 0.845,2320.840.900.90
1974 0.855,3170.870.890.89
1975 0.865,4510.960.930.91
1976 0.835,7820.970.970.98
1977 0.846,2341.021.031.02
1978 0.846,3471.031.051.08
1979 0.846,0341.000.970.96
1980 0.846,0351.050.990.99
1981 0.865,7120.940.890.88
1982 0.905,2390.850.840.82
1983 0.915,4040.830.800.76
1984 0.915,9770.760.760.75
1985 0.926,8130.670.670.64
1986 0.927,3450.790.800.70
1987 1.007,4980.830.830.75
1988 1.027,4320.810.760.67
1989 1.027,3340.760.770.69
1990 1.016,8820.750.690.67
1991 1.016,4840.880.800.79
1992 1.016,8070.800.800.79
1993 0.997,2310.870.850.76
1994 0.997,5940.830.810.76
1995 0.998,0300.690.610.56
1996 0.998,0220.740.670.61
1997 0.967,7640.680.630.62
1998 0.936,9840.660.560.55
1999 0.937,1900.700.610.64
2000 0.946,0580.460.390.32
2001 0.955,6610.470.430.39
2002 0.955,9050.610.600.45
2003 1.026,1470.690.640.57
2004 1.026,3470.740.810.77
Std deviation 0.080.140.150.17
Total 0.90256,3600.810.790.76

Column (1) reports the tax preference ratio ρ=(1-td)/(1-tg) measuring the tax preference of accrued capital gains over dividends for U.S. corporate stock (weighted by ownership) from 1963 to 2004. This ratio is from Poterba (2004).

Column (2) reports the annual number of regular taxable dividend nominal increases or initiations in the sample.

Columns (3), (4), and (5) report the corresponding time-series measures of the (market-adjusted) dividend increase premium Δ P/D. Column (3) reports the median. Column (4) reports the weighted mean (weight is ΔD/P.). Column (5) reports the mean (trimmed for the smallest 25 percent dividend increase to price ratio events).

2.2   Dividend Increase Announcement-Day Returns and Taxes

Corporations distribute profits to shareholders in two main forms: dividends and share repurchases. In a world without taxes and with perfect information, share repurchases and dividends are equivalent. However, the market appears to treat these two forms of payout very differently in practice. Reducing or terminating regular dividend payments carries a very negative signal and is heavily penalized by investors. In contrast, share repurchases (or one-time special dividend payments) are not seen as a commitment to continue paying in the future, and accordingly announcements of repurchases generate far lower excess returns than announcements of dividends.





© Cambridge University Press

Table of Contents

Contributors; Preface; 1. The effect of taxes on market responses to dividend announcements and payments: what can we learn from the 2003 dividend tax cut? Raj Chetty, Joseph Rosenberg and Emmanuel Saez; Comments Gustavo Grullon; Comments Douglas J. Skinner; 2. Dissecting dividend decisions: some clues about the effects of dividend taxation from recent UK reforms Stephen R. Bond, Michael P. Devereux and Alexander Klemm; Comments Roger Gordon; Comments James Poterba; 3. The 2003 dividend tax cuts and the value of the firm: an event study Alan J. Auerbach and Kevin A. Hassett; Comments William G. Gale; Comments George R. Zodrow; 4. How elastic is the corporate income tax base? Jonathan Gruber and Joshua Rauh; Comments Jane Gravelle; Comments Casey B. Mulligan; 5. An empirical examination of corporate tax noncompliance Michelle Hanlon, Lillian Mills and Joel Slemrod; Comments Joseph Bankman; Comments Brian Erard; 6. On the extent, growth, and efficiency consequences of state business tax planning Donald Bruce, John Deskins and William F. Fox; Comments William M. Gentry; Comments Charles E. McLure, Jr; 7. Corporate taxation and international competition James R. Hines Jr; Comments Jack M. Mintz; Comments John Douglas Wilson; 8. The changing role of auditors in corporate tax planning Edward L. Maydew and Douglas A. Shackelford; Comments Steven N. Kaplan; Comments Richard Sansing; 9. Taxation and the evolution of aggregate corporate ownership concentration Mihir A. Desai, Dhammika Dharmapala and Winnie Fung; Comments Jeffrey R. Brown; Comments Jeff Strnad; Index.
From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews