Capitalism 3.0: A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons

Capitalism 3.0: A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons

by Peter Barnes
Capitalism 3.0: A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons

Capitalism 3.0: A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons

by Peter Barnes

eBook

$13.49  $17.99 Save 25% Current price is $13.49, Original price is $17.99. You Save 25%.

Available on Compatible NOOK devices, the free NOOK App and in My Digital Library.
WANT A NOOK?  Explore Now

Related collections and offers

LEND ME® See Details

Overview

The sustainable business expert and author of Climate Solutions presents a plan to upgrade capitalism to meet the challenges of the twenty-first century.

The commons—the collective natural and cultural resources that belong to all of humanity—is currently under siege. It is being squandered under our current version of corporate, globalized capitalism. This is Capitalism 2.0. And, according to Peter Barnes, we’re long overdue for an upgrade.

Our current operating system gives too much power to profit-maximizing corporations that devour the commons and distribute most of their profits to a sliver of the population. Barnes proposes a revised operating system, Capitalism 3.0, that protects the commons while preserving the many strengths of capitalism as we know it. His major innovation is the commons trust, a market based legal entity with the power to limit the use of the commons, charge rent, and pay dividends—in both cash and services—to everyone.

In Barnes' vision, an array of commons trusts would institutionalize our obligations to future generations, fellow citizens, and nature. Once established, they'd use markets and property rights to create a better world for us all.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9781605091648
Publisher: Berrett-Koehler Publishers
Publication date: 04/14/2022
Sold by: Barnes & Noble
Format: eBook
Pages: 216
File size: 3 MB

About the Author

Peter Barnes is a writer and entrepreneur who has started and run several successful businesses. He cofounded Working Assets Long Distance (now Credo Mobile) and is the author numerous other titles, including Who Owns the Sky?, Pawns: The Plight of the Citizen-Soldier, and most recently With Liberty and Dividends for All.

Read an Excerpt

Capitalism 3.0

A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons
By Peter Barnes

Berrett-Koehler Publishers

Copyright © 2006 Peter Barnes
All right reserved.




Chapter One

Time to Upgrade

Society is indeed a contract ... between those who are living, those who are dead, and those who are to be born. -Edmund Burke (1792)

For the first time in history, the natural world we leave our children will be frightfully worse than the one we inherited from our parents. This isn't just because we're using the planet as if there were no tomorrow-that's been going on for centuries. It's because the cumulative weight of our past and present malfeasance has brought us to several tipping points. Nature has her tolerance limits, and we've reached many of them. In some cases, very possibly, we've passed them.

The State of the World

Consider, for example, our atmosphere. It's not just today's pollution that hurts, it's the accumulation of fumes we've been pouring into the air for centuries. This has already caused ice caps to melt, hurricanes to gain ferocity, and the Gulf Stream to weaken. Almost universally, the world's scientists warn that far worse lies ahead. The question our generation faces is: Will we change our economic system voluntarily, or let the atmosphere change it for us?

Consider also what scientists call biodiversity. The earth is a tiny island of life in a cold, dark universe. We humans share this magical island with millions ofother species, most of whom we haven't met. Each of these species fills a niche and contributes to the web of life. Yet little by little, we're pushing the others out of their living spaces. The result is a wave of extinctions comparable to that which wiped out the dinosaurs sixty-five million years ago. The difference is that, while the dinosaurs' extinction was triggered by a freak event, the current extinctions are being caused by our everyday activities.

And it's not just other species we're endangering. As anthropologists Jared Diamond and Ronald Wright recently reminded us, past human civilizations (Sumer, Rome, the Maya, Easter Island) did on a smaller scale what our own economic system seems bent on doing today-they destroyed their resource bases and crashed. The pattern is hauntingly familiar. First, the civilization finds a formula-agriculture, irrigation, fishing, capitalism-for extracting value from ecosystems. It applies the formula again and again, and because the formula works so well, the civilization's leaders become blindly attached to it. Eventually, the key resources on which the economic system depends become depleted and the inflexible civilization collapses like a house of cards.

I'm not suggesting we're doomed to repeat this pattern. Because we can revise our economic operating system, we have a chance to avert it. But let's not belittle the risks we face today-they're real and imminent.

What I Mean By the Commons

When most people think of the commons, they imagine a pasture where animals graze. That's an antiquated notion, and not what I have in mind. In this book I use the commons as a generic term, like the market or the state. It refers to all the gifts we inherit or create together.

This notion of the commons designates a set of assets that have two characteristics: they're all gifts, and they're all shared. A gift is something we receive, as opposed to something we make or earn. A shared gift is one we receive as members of a community, as opposed to individually. Examples of such gifts include air, water, ecosystems, languages, music, holidays, money, law, mathematics, parks, the Internet, and much more.

These diverse gifts are like a river with three broad tributaries: nature, community, and culture (see figure 1.1). This long-flowing river precedes and surrounds capitalism, and adds immense value to it (and to us). Indeed, we literally can't live without it, and we certainly can't live well.

There's another quality to assets in the commons: we have a joint obligation to preserve them. That's because future generations will need them to live, and live well, just as we do. And our generation has no right to say, "These gifts end here." This shared responsibility introduces a moral factor that doesn't apply to other economic assets: it requires us to consider whether an asset is worthy of long-term preservation, and if it is, to preserve it as best we can. Markets don't see this as a moral question, to be decided by a community or society; they see it as a purely mathematical question, to be decided by an asset owner. If an asset yields a competitive return, it should be kept alive; if it doesn't, it deserves to die.

By contrast, assets in the commons are meant to be preserved regardless of their return to capital. Just as we receive them as shared gifts, so we have a duty to pass them on in at least the same condition as we received them. If we can add to their value, so much the better, but at a minimum we must not degrade them, and we certainly have no right to destroy them.

It's important to note that this notion of the commons embraces assets that are human-made as well as natural, intangible as well as tangible, large as well as small. Often they are complex systems. What makes them part of the commons isn't what they're made of, but how we, as humans, relate to them.

I use a few similar-sounding terms in this book that should be clarified here as well.

COMMON WEALTH

By common wealth, I mean the monetary and nonmonetary value of the commons. Like stockholders' equity in a corporation, it may increase or decrease from year to year depending on how well the commons is managed.

COMMON PROPERTY

By common property, I mean a class of human-made rights that lies somewhere between private property and state property. Like private property, common property arises when the state recognizes it. Unlike private property, it's inclusive rather than exclusive-it strives to share ownership as widely as possible, rather than as narrowly as possible.

THE COMMONS SECTOR

By the commons sector, I mean an organized sector of our economy. It embraces some of the gifts we inherit together, but not all. In effect, it's a subset of the given commons that we consciously organize according to commons principles. It's small at the moment. The point of this book is that we should enlarge it.

The Tragedy of the Commons Isn't What You Think

If you heard about the commons before you picked up this book, your impressions may have been shaped by a 1968 article called "The Tragedy of the Commons." In that article, biologist Garrett Hardin used the metaphor of an unmanaged pasture to suggest a root cause of many planetary problems.

The rational herdsman concludes that the only sensible course for him to pursue is to add another animal to his herd. And another.... But this is the conclusion reached by each and every rational herdsman sharing a commons. Therein is the tragedy. Each man is locked into a system that compels him to increase his herd without limit-in a world that is limited. Ruin is the destination toward which all men rush, each pursuing his own best interest.... Freedom in a commons brings ruin to all.

Hardin's notion of tragedy was taken from philosopher Alfred North Whitehead, who in turn drew upon Aristotle. According to Whitehead, the essence of tragedy is "the remorseless working of things." In Hardin's view, commons are fated to self-destruct. There's nothing humans can do in the context of the commons to halt this inexorable outcome.

Hardin was right about humanity's unrelenting destruction of nature, but wrong about its cause and inexorability. He blamed the commons itself, when the true destroyer was, and remains, human-made forces outside the commons. In Hardin's hypothetical, the commons does nothing to protect itself against those forces. It's completely "free," which is to say, unmanaged. But there's no inherent reason why commons can't be managed as commons.

Contrary to the picture painted by Hardin, medieval European commons (which included not only pastures but forests and streams) were far from unmanaged. They had rules barring access to outsiders and limiting use by villagers. For example, a rule that persists today in many Swiss villages is that villagers can't graze in common pasture more animals than they can feed over winter on their own land. A managed commons, in other words, isn't inherently self-destructive. The real danger to the commons is enclosure and trespass by outsiders.

Our Economic Operating System

An operating system is a set of instructions that orchestrates the moving parts of a larger system. The most familiar example is a computer operating system that coordinates the keyboard, screen, processor, and so on. Operating system instructions are written in code that can reside in electrons (as in a computer), chemicals (as in genes), or social norms and laws. Frequently, parts of the code can be expressed mathematically.

Just as our Constitution sets the rules for our democracy, so our economic operating system sets the rules for capitalism. Our economic operating system isn't as widely understood as our Constitution, nor is it spelled out in one concise document. It's visible if you look for it, but it's hidden in a shroud of statutes and court decisions. Still, like the Constitution, it's there-and it runs the mercantile life of our nation.

I like to think of our economic operating system as analogous to the rules of the board game Monopoly. It defines such things as starting conditions, rules of play, and the distribution of rewards and risk. It defines them partly through law, and partly by assigning fictional things called property and money.

All operating systems contain feedback loops-if certain conditions are detected, do this; if others are detected, do that. These feedback loops can be virtuous (the reaction fixes the problem) or vicious (the reaction makes the problem worse). A stable system has lots of virtuous loops and is good at weeding out vicious loops.

Sometimes, in human-made systems, virtuous loops have to be consciously added. Consider the steam engine of eighteenth-century inventor James Watt. Watt's design included two critical mechanisms: the steam-driven engine itself, and a centrifugal governor to keep the engine from getting out of control. When the latter detects a potentially dangerous behavior-speeding-it automatically corrects that behavior.

Illth and Thneeds

More than a century ago, English economist John Ruskin observed that the same economic system that creates glittering wealth also spawns what he called illth-poverty, pollution, despair, illness. It makes life comfortable for some, but it does so at considerable discomfort to others.

Modern economists' term for illth is negative externalities. By this they mean the costs of economic transactions that are "external" to the parties involved. The classic example is a factory that dumps effluent into a river. Unlike homeowners who pay for garbage pickup, the factory's owners pay nothing for disposing their waste into the river. But humans and other creatures living downstream do pay a cost. Plants and animals suffer and die, while cities have to build expensive treatment plants. From the standpoint of the factory owner, none of this matters. But from the standpoints of nature and society, these are negative externalities. (There can, sometimes, be positive externalities-for example, if your neighbor repaints her house, that may increase the value of yours.)

For a long time, economists assured us that the wealth spewed out by our economic machine was so great, and the illth so trivial, that we didn't need to worry about negative externalities. If this was ever true, it's assuredly true no longer. Contemporary climate change is, quintessentially, a problem of negative externalities. We pay owners of land beneath which fossil fuels lie. We pay drillers, refiners, transporters, and retailers. But we don't pay nature, or anyone else, for dumping heat-trapping gases into the atmosphere. We shift this cost to our children, and take a free ride. We party, they pay.

What's more, many negative externalities aren't even the result of meeting genuine human needs. The word thneed doesn't appear in any economics text, but it's symbolic of our modern predicament. The word was coined by Theodor Geisel-better known as Dr. Seuss-in his children's fable The Lorax, a story written in comic style but actually quite a serious tract. Thneed means, roughly, a thing we want but don't really need. As many parents will recall, The Lorax pits a dynamic entrepreneur (the Once-ler) against the pesky Lorax, a critter who "speaks for the trees." The Once-ler makes thneeds by cutting down truffula trees. When the Lorax protests, the Once-ler replies:

I'm being quite useful. This thing is a Thneed. A Thneed's a Fine-Something-That-All-People-Need!

Economists have no technical term for thneed; they assume that all "demand" in the economy is equivalent, as long as it's backed with money. Yet surely it would be helpful to differentiate. One can imagine an axis running from needs to thneeds. On one end are such things as food, shelter, basic transportation, and health care. On the other end are Coca-Cola, iPods, and Hummers. (Significantly, needs are generic, while thneeds are typically branded.) Filling needs contributes more to human well-being than does selling thneeds, yet our economic system increasingly devotes scarce resources to thneeds.

Why do we have so much illth and so many thneeds? Because our economic operating system is far out of balance. On one side, representing owners of capital, are powerful profit-maximizing corporations. On the other side, representing future generations, nonhuman species, and millions of humans with unmet needs, are-almost nothing. The system lacks institutions that preserve shared inheritances, charge corporations for degrading nature, or boost the "demanding" power of people whose basic needs are ignored. Hence the system generates ever more illth, waste, and ever-widening disparities between rich and poor.

Upgrading Our System

Can we imagine, design, and install an upgraded operating system that fixes these tragic flaws? This may seem a far-fetched dream. But consider that something comparable happened before, in 1935, with the enactment of Social Security.

Like the changes I'm suggesting in this volume, Social Security is an intergenerational compact, engraved into our economic operating system. It was imagined, designed, and installed early in the twentieth century in response to what was then a looming crisis: the impoverishment of millions too old to work. The basic contract was, and remains, simple: active workers collectively support retired workers, and in return are supported in old age by the next generation of workers. For seventy years, this contract has been administered without scandal or waste by a trust fund that has never missed a payment. Thanks to this operating system upgrade, extreme old-age poverty, once rampant, is largely a thing of the past.

What we need now is a comparable system upgrade, this time to fix capitalism's disregard for nature, future generations, and the nonelderly poor.

Premises of This Book

All thought processes start with premises and flow to conclusions. Here are the main premises of this book.

1. WE HAVE A CONTRACT

Each generation has a moral contract with the next to pass on the gifts it has inherited in at least as good condition as it received them. The gifts we inherit fall into three broad categories: nature, community, and culture. The first category includes air, water, and ecosystems. The second includes laws, infrastructure, and the many ways in which we connect with one another. The third includes language, art, and science. All of these gifts are immensely valuable, and need to be preserved if not enhanced.

(Continues...)



Excerpted from Capitalism 3.0 by Peter Barnes Copyright © 2006 by Peter Barnes. Excerpted by permission.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews