Capital Ideas Evolving

Capital Ideas Evolving

by Peter L. Bernstein
Capital Ideas Evolving

Capital Ideas Evolving

by Peter L. Bernstein

eBook

$3.99  $29.99 Save 87% Current price is $3.99, Original price is $29.99. You Save 87%.

Available on Compatible NOOK devices, the free NOOK App and in My Digital Library.
WANT A NOOK?  Explore Now

Related collections and offers

LEND ME® See Details

Overview

"A lot has happened in the financial markets since 1992, when Peter Bernstein wrote his seminal Capital Ideas. Happily, Peter has taken up his facile pen again to describe these changes, a virtual revolution in the practice of investing that relies heavily on complex mathematics, derivatives, hedging, and hyperactive trading. This fine and eminently readable book is unlikely to be surpassed as the definitive chronicle of a truly historic era." John C. Bogle, founder of The Vanguard Group and author, The Little Book of Common Sense Investing "Just as Dante could not have understood or survived the perils of the Inferno without Virgil to guide him, investors today need Peter Bernstein to help find their way across dark and shifting ground. No one alive understands Wall Street's intellectual history better, and that makes Bernstein our best and wisest guide to the future. He is the only person who could have written this book; thank goodness he did." Jason Zweig, Investing Columnist, Money magazine "Another must-read from Peter Bernstein! This well-written and thought-provoking book provides valuable insights on how key finance theories have evolved from their ivory tower formulation to profitable application by portfolio managers. This book will certainly be read with keen interest by, and undoubtedly influence, a wide range of participants in international finance." Dr. Mohamed A. El-Erian, President and CEO of Harvard Management Company, Deputy Treasurer of Harvard University, and member of the faculty of the Harvard Business School "Reading Capital Ideas Evolving is an experience not to be missed. Peter Bernstein's knowledge of the principal characters-the giants in the development of investment theory and practice-brings this subject to life." Linda B. Strumpf, Vice President and Chief Investment Officer, The Ford Foundation "With great clarity, Peter Bernstein introduces us to the insights of investment giants, and explains how they transformed financial theory into portfolio practice. This is not just a tale of money and models; it is a fascinating and contemporary story about people and the power of their ideas." Elroy Dimson, BGI Professor of Investment Management, London Business School "Capital Ideas Evolving provides us with a unique appreciation for the pervasive impact that the theory of modern finance has had on the development of our capital markets. Peter Bernstein once again has produced a masterpiece that is must reading for practitioners, educators and students of finance." Andr F. Perold, Professor of Finance, Harvard Business School

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9781118046203
Publisher: Wiley
Publication date: 08/22/2023
Sold by: Barnes & Noble
Format: eBook
Pages: 304
File size: 1 MB

About the Author

Peter L. Bernstein is President of Peter L. Bernstein, Inc., an investment con-sultant firm he founded in 1973, after many years of managing billions of dollars in individual and institutional portfolios. Bernstein is also the author of ten books on economics and finance, including the bestselling Capital Ideas, Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk, and The Power of Gold: The History of an Obsession. He has lectured widely throughout the United States and abroad, and has received the highest honors from his peers in the investment profession.

Read an Excerpt

1

Who Could Design a Brain . . .

Alfred Marshall, the great Victorian economist, opens his Principles of Economics with these words:

Economics . . . examines that part of individual and social action which is most closely connected with the attainment and with the use of the material requisites of wellbeing. Thus it is on the one side a study of wealth; and, on the other, and more important side, a part of the study of man.

Marshall's Principles were to set the tone of economics for the next half century. In this work, despite his noble words in the quotation above, he made the study of man secondary to the study of wealth. Under all conditions, man in classical economics is an automaton capable of objective reasoning. Furthermore, disagreement about the future— a fundamental feature of the study of man—has no place in this particular study of wealth. Marshall's approach was finally dislodged, with great difficulty and after many years of dispute, by the publication in 1936 of his student John Maynard Keynes's masterwork, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.

The bundle of ideas, models, concepts, and systems embodied in the theoretical structure of modern finance—what I describe as Capital Ideas—appeared between 1952 and 1973. They owe little to Keynes and almost everything to Marshall. The entire underlying structure of Capital Ideas rests on one overriding assumption: Investors have no difficulty in making optimal choices in the bewildering jumble of facts, rumors, discontinuities, vagueness, and black uncertainty that make up the real world around us.

Over time, this tension between an ideal concept of human rationality and the coarse reality of our daily lives has become an increasingly contentious issue. How much do we know about how people in the real world arrive at decisions and make choices? How great are the differences between the theoretical assumptions and the real world? And do those differences matter?

Although these questions have always been central to understanding the way investors behave and how their responses affect the performance of financial markets, no one made any systematic effort to provide the answers until the mid-1960s. The most significant and inf luential effort to approach these problems, a field of study that has come to be known as Behavioral Finance, began to take shape quite by accident when two junior psychology professors at Hebrew University in Jerusalem, Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, happened to compare notes one day about their work and their life experiences. The hugely productive result of their friendship and subsequent collaboration has created a competing vision to the rational model of how people make choices and reach decisions under conditions of uncertainty.** The essence of this work is the study of man—of human behavior. As Kahneman and Tversky wrote in 1992: "Theories of choice are at best approximate and incomplete. . . . Choice is a constructive and contingent process. When faced with a complex problem, people . . . use computational shortcuts and editing operations."1 The result is a decision-making process differing in many aspects from the assumptions of Capital Ideas.

It would be a mistake to accuse Kahneman and Tversky of tarring all humanity with the black brush of irrationality. That was never the case, as Kahneman's autobiography makes clear: "The interpretation of our work as a broad attack on human rationality rather than a critique of the rational-agent model attracted much opposition [to our efforts], some quite harsh and dismissive."2 As Kahneman put the point to me, "The failure in the rational model is . . . in the human brain it requires. Who could design a brain that could perform in the way this model mandates? Every single one of us would have to know and understand everything, completely, and at once."† He expresses this position even more precisely in writing:

I am now quick to reject any description of our work as demonstrating human irrationality. When the occasion arises, I carefully explain that research on heuristics and biases only refutes an unrealistic conception of rationality, which identifies it as comprehensive coherence. . . . In my current view, the study of judgment biases requires attention to the interplay between intuitive and ref lective thinking, which sometimes allows biased judgments and sometimes overrides or corrects them.3

* * *

Kahneman's and Tversky's published papers, both individually and jointly, constitute an imposing compendium of evidence, ideas, and axioms of human behavior in the process of decision making. One of the most interesting features of Kahneman's and Tversky's work is the innovative nature of their discoveries. The patterns of human nature they discuss must have existed since the beginning of time, but no one before them had caught their vision. They unleashed a far larger flood of research from other academics and, over time, from the practitioner side as well.

In highly compressed fashion, the rest of this chapter conducts a survey of Behavioral Finance based on a small but characteristic sample of these investigations. The implications of this survey for investment are fascinating, but along the way the material also provides a mirror in which we see ourselves probably more often than we would like. The real issue is this: How much damage has this attack inf licted on the standard theories and models of f inance? Do the critique of the rational-agent model and the demonstrations of its empirical failures render my book, Capital Ideas, useless and at best obsolete? Or, in a more practical mode, do the teachings of Behavioral Finance lead us to alpha—to an excess return on our investments after adjustment for risk? Final judgment must await the presentation of the evidence. But final judgment will be rendered.

Before moving on, a separate point is worth making. The focus of the discussion so far has been on how the findings of Behavioral Finance relate to each of us as an investor. But a deeper issue is also involved, set forth by John Campbell of the Economics Department at Harvard in his presidential address to the American Finance Association in January 2006:

Even if asset prices are set efficiently, investment mistakes can have large welfare costs for households. . . . They may greatly reduce the welfare gains that can be realized from the current period of financial innovation. . . . If household finance can achieve good understanding of the sources of investment mistakes, it may be possible for the field to contribute ideas to limit the costs of these mistakes.

* * *

A story that Kahneman recounted in the course of his address accepting the Nobel Prize provides a typical example of the "computational shortcuts and editing operations" we use in our attempts to make choices in complex problems. Kahneman had conducted an experiment with two different audiences. Although he offered both audiences an identical set of choices, he presented these choices in different settings that led to strikingly different results.

He asked each audience to imagine a community preparing for the outbreak of a dreaded disease. The experts have predicted the disease will kill 600 people if nothing is done, but they offer two different programs to deal with the contingencies.

Under Program A, 200 people will be saved. Under Program B, there is a one-third possibility that all 600 people will be saved and a two-thirds' probability that everybody will die. Kahneman found that the audience presented with these choices overwhelmingly favored Program A, on the basis that the gamble in Program B was too risky. The certainty that 200 people would be saved was preferable to a two thirds' chance that everybody will die.

Then Kahneman presented the identical choices to the other audience, but in a revised setting. Under Plan C, 400 people will die. Under Plan D, there is a one-third chance that nobody will die and a two thirds' probability that 600 people will die. Now the audience's choice was for Plan D. The gamble, in its Plan D garb, now seems preferable to Plan C, in which it is certain 400 people will die.

How can we account for these opposing sets of responses to what are identical choices and probabilities? As Kahneman explains it, nobody has ever figured out a perfect technique for dealing with uncertainty. Consequently, in making choices and decisions, we tend to overweight certain outcomes relative to uncertain outcomes, even when the uncertain outcomes have a high probability. In the case of the first audience, the certainty of saving 200 out of 600 people is "disproportionately attractive." In the case of the second audience, accepting the certain death of 400 out of 600 people is "disproportionately aversive."

Kahneman and Tversky have defined these kinds of inconsistencies in decision making as "failure of invariance." The failure of invariance comes in many colors, with endless variations of the theme.* Invariance means that if A is preferred to B and B is preferred to C, rational people should prefer A to C. In the case above, if the rational decision in the first set is 200 lives saved for certain, saving 200 lives for certain should be the rational decision in the second set as well.

Kahneman and Tversky use the expression, "framing," to describe these kinds of failures of invariance, which are widely prevalent. In the example of the outbreak of the dreaded disease, the audience in the first case framed their responses around how many people would live, while the second audience framed their responses around how many people might die. Kahneman's Nobel address defines framing as "the passive acceptance of the formulation given." And then he adds, "Invariance cannot be achieved by a finite mind."4

* * *

Richard Thaler of the University of Chicago, one of Kahneman's and Tversky's earliest and most articulate disciples, describes an amusing example of the failure of invariance involving money. Thaler proposed to students in one of his classes that they had just won $30. Now they could choose between two outcomes: a coin f lip where the individual would win $9 on heads or lose $9 on tails, or no f lip of the coin at all. The coin f lip was the choice of 70 percent of the students. When his next class came along, Thaler asked the students to assume that they had a starting wealth of zero. Now they could choose between these two options. The first was a coin f lip where the individual wins $39 on heads and $21 on tails. The second was $30 for certain. Only 43 percent of the students chose the coin f lip; the majority preferred the $30 for certain.

When you study the options offered to both classes, you will find that the payoffs are identical. Whether the starting wealth is $30 or zero, the students in both cases are going to end up with either $39 or $21 versus ending up with $30 for sure. Yet the majorities of the two classes made entirely different choices, resulting in a failure of invariance.

Thaler ascribes this inconsistency to what he calls "the house money effect." If you have money in your pocket, you will choose the gamble. If you have no money in your pocket, you would rather have the $30 for certain than take the risk of ending up with $21.5

In the real world, the house money effect matters. Investors who are already wealthy are willing to take significant risks because they can absorb the losses, while investors with limited means will invest conservatively because of fear they cannot afford to lose the little they have.

This is precisely the opposite of how people with different wealth levels should arrive at decisions. The wealthy investor is already wealthy and does not need to take the gamble. If investors with only a small amount of savings lose it all, this would probably make little difference, but a killing on the small accumulation could change their lives.

Another investment-oriented version of the distortions caused by framing resulted in an experiment conducted in 2001 by Thaler and his frequent coauthor Shlomo Benartzi of UCLA.6 Participants were divided into three separate groups with no contact among the groups.

Each group was given a choice of two fund offerings for their retirement plans. One group was offered a fund holding just stocks and a fund holding just bonds. The second group was offered a fund holding just stocks and a balanced fund that includes stocks and bonds. The third group was offered a bond fund and a balanced fund.

Even though these choices were for retirement funds that should have had roughly the same asset allocation decisions, the three groups ended up with wide differences in portfolio structures. The differences arose because the 50-50 choice is always popular: It seems like common sense; it looks like diversification; and it avoids the complex decision about how assets should be allocated in a retirement fund. The consequences were dramatic. The first group, choosing between a stock fund and a bond fund, ended up with an average allocation of 54 percent to equities. The second group, offered a stock fund and a balanced fund, also leaned in the 50-50 direction between the two funds, but ended up with an average allocation of 73 percent to equities and only 27 percent to bonds, because half the balanced fund was already invested in equities. The third group, offered a bond fund and a balanced fund, ended up with an average of 65 percent in bonds and only 35 percent in equities.

The experiment demonstrates that framing determined the decision making among the three groups. The proper approach should have been to consider the different expected rates of return and risks of each asset class and to see through to the underlying structure of the balanced fund in making the final choice. Fifty percent to each asset class might not have been optimal, but it would have been a sensible choice for someone with no experience or no understanding of the different risk return trade-offs between stocks and bonds. In fact, however, the design of the offering dominated. Most of the participants were unwilling to make the intellectual effort to see through the 50-50 allocation of the balanced fund and recognize that the true asset allocation was a long way from 50-50.

This experiment was not just an artificial effort to find out how people make choices where framing is likely to dominate. The 50-50 choice tends to dominate at TIAA-CREF, the huge retirement fund for university faculties. Here, at least, there is professional advice available to help participants avoid the simplifications of framing and, instead, to understand the structure that would best suit their needs. But I must also report that one of the famous developers of the theory of finance, whose current activities receive an entire chapter in this book, has confessed he has also made the 50-50 choice at TIAA-CREF.

Continues …

* Tversky died at the age of 59 in 1996. Kahneman, now at Princeton University, was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 2002.

**Unless otherwise specified, all quotations come from personal interviews or personal correspondence.

†Campbell (2006).

‡See, in particular, Thaler (1991), which describes many examples of the failure of invariance and framing.

Table of Contents


Preface     ix
A Note on Usage     xx
The Behavioral Attack
Who Could Design a Brain...     3
The Strange Paradox of Behavioral Finance: "Neoclassical Theory Is a Theory of Sharks"     19
The Theoreticians
Paul A. Samuelson: The Worldly Philosopher     37
The Institutionalists
Robert C. Merton: "Risk Is Not an Add-On"     47
Andrew Lo: "The Only Part of Economics That Really Works"     58
Robert Shiller: The People's Risk Manager     65
The Engineers
Bill Sharper: "It's Dangerous to Think of Risk as a Number"     91
Harry Markowitz: "You Have a Little World"     100
Myron Scholes: "Omega Has a Nice Ring to It"     110
The Practitioners
Barclays Global Investors: "It Was an Evangelical Undertaking"     127
The Yale Endowment Fund: Uninstitutional Behavior     148
CAPM II: The Great Alpha Dream Machine: We Don't See Expected Returns     165
Making Alpha Portable: "That's Become the New Mantra"     179
Martin Leibowitz: CAPM in a New Suit of Clothes     196
Goldman Sachs Asset Management: "I Know the Invisible Hand Is Still There"     214
Capital Ideas Tomorrow
Nothing Stands Still     237
Notes     247
Bibliography     252
Acknowledgments     261
Index     263

What People are Saying About This

"A lot has happened in the financial markets since 1992, when Peter Bernstein wrote his seminal Capital Ideas. Happily, Peter has taken up his facile pen again to describe these changes, a virtual revolution in the practice of investing that relies heavily on complex mathematics, derivatives, hedging, and hyperactive trading. This fine and eminently readable book is unlikely to be surpassed as the definitive chronicle of a truly historic era."
— John C. Bogle, founder of The Vanguard Group and author, The Little Book of Common Sense Investing

"Just as Dante could not have understood or survived the perils of the Inferno without Virgil to guide him, investors today need Peter Bernstein to help find their way across dark and shifting ground. No one alive understands Wall Street's intellectual history better, and that makes Bernstein our best and wisest guide to the future. He is the only person who could have written this book; thank goodness he did."
— Jason Zweig, Investing Columnist, Money magazine

"Another must-read from Peter Bernstein! This well-written and thought-provoking book provides valuable insights on how key finance theories have evolved from their ivory tower formulation to profitable application by portfolio managers. This book will certainly be read with keen interest by, and undoubtedly influence, a wide range of participants in international finance."
— Dr. Mohamed A. El-Erian, President and CEO of Harvard Management Company, Deputy Treasurer of Harvard University, and member of the faculty of the Harvard Business School

"Reading Capital Ideas Evolving is an experience not to be missed. Peter Bernstein's knowledge of the principal characters—the giants in the development of investment theory and practice—brings this subject to life."
— Linda B. Strumpf, Vice President and Chief Investment Officer, The Ford Foundation

"With great clarity, Peter Bernstein introduces us to the insights of investment giants, and explains how they transformed financial theory into portfolio practice. This is not just a tale of money and models; it is a fascinating and contemporary story about people and the power of their ideas."
— Elroy Dimson, BGI Professor of Investment Management, London Business School

"Capital Ideas Evolving provides us with a unique appreciation for the pervasive impact that the theory of modern finance has had on the development of our capital markets. Peter Bernstein once again has produced a masterpiece that is must reading for practitioners, educators and students of finance."
— André F. Perold, Professor of Finance, Harvard Business School

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews